从“命令—控制”到“市场调节”的环境管制模式研究及启示
——以美国酸雨治理为例Research and enlightment of the environmental regulation model from “command-and-control” to “market-based instrument”
-
摘要: 美国酸雨治理模式的变迁过程在美国乃至世界环境与经济史上均具有典型意义。随着1990年“酸雨计划”的出台,美国完成了酸雨治理由“命令—控制”向“市场调节”模式的转变,也为世界各国在探索经济发展与环境污染治理的问题上提供了一个历史“范式”。在对美国酸雨治理模式的演变过程进行阶段性历史分析的基础上,从2种典型的环境管制模式的主要特征入手,阐释“命令—控制”模式最终被“市场调节”模式所取代的必然性,对于研究我国环境管制模式的转型问题具有重要意义。Abstract: The transition of the acid rain regulation model in the United States has typical significance both in the environmental history and economic history of the United States and even the world. With the enactment of the “Acid Rain Program” in 1990, the United States completed the transition of acid rain regulation from a “command-and-control” model to a “market-based instrument” model and provided a historical “paradigm” for countries around the world to balance economic development and environmental regulation. The transition of acid rain regulation models in the United States was analyzed from a phased historical point. The main characteristics of two typical environmental regulations models were identified, and the inevitability of the “command-control” model being replaced by the “market-based instrument” model was explained. It has great significance to study the transition of environmental regulation models in our country.
-
表 1 国家环境空气质量标准
Table 1. National Ambient Air Quality Standards
污染物 国家一级环境质量标准 国家二级环境质量标准 均值类型 标准浓度水平 均值类型 标准浓度水平 一氧化碳 8小时 10 mg·m−3 未设定 无 1小时 40 mg·m−3 未设定 无 铅 平均每季最大值 1.5 μg·m−3 平均每季最大值 1.5 μg·m−3 氮氧化物 每年算数平均值 100 μg·m−3 每年算数平均值 100 μg·m−3 臭氧 每天1小时平均最大值 235 μg·m−3 每天1小时平均最大值 235 μg·m−3 颗粒物(PM10) 每年算数平均值 50 μg·m−3 每年算数平均值 50 μg·m−3 24小时 150 μg·m−3 24小时 150 μg·m−3 二氧化硫 每年算数平均值 80 μg·m−3 3小时 1300 μg·m−3 24小时 365 μg·m−3 -
[1] SINGH A, AGRAWAL M. Acid rain and its ecological consequences[J]. Journal of Environmental Biology, 2008, 29(1): 15 − 24. [2] FLIPPEN J B. Nixon and the environment[M]. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, 2000. [3] REITZE A. Air pollution control law: compliance and enforcement[M]. Washington D. C. : Environmental Law Institute, 2001. [4] PIERCE R J. Regulation, deregulation, federalism, and administrative law: agency power to preempt state regulation[J]. University of Pittsburgh Law Review, 1985, 46(607): 607 − 671. [5] United States Congress. Public Law 91-604(1970)[A]. Washington D. C. : United States Government Priting Office, 1970. [6] United States Congress. Public Law 95-95(1977)[A]. Washington D. C. : United States Government Priting Office, 1980. [7] PORTNEY P R, STAVINS R N. Public policies for environmental protection[M]. Washington D. C. : Resources for the Future, 2000. [8] National Archives of the United States. Office of Federal Register. [EB]. Federal Register, 1973, 38(178): 25679-1984. [9] VESTIGO J R. Acid rain and tall stack regulation under the Clean Air Act[J]. Environmental Law, 1985, 15(4): 711 − 744. [10] SULLIVAN J L. Beyond the bargaining table: Canada's use of section 115 of the United States Clean Air Act to prevent acid rain[J]. Cornell International Law Journal, 1983, 16(193): 193 − 227. [11] CUTLER A C, ZACHER M W. Canadian foreign policy and international economic regimes[M]. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 1992. [12] United States Court of Appeals. West Penn Power Co. v. Train, 538 F. 2d 1020[R]. Washington D. C. : District of Third Circuit, 1976. [13] United States Environmental Protection Agency. Acid rain program, SO2 reduction[EB/OL]. [2021-12-01]. https://www.epa.gov/acidrain/acid-rain-program/. [14] United States Environmental Protection Agency. The opt-in program: overview for combustion sources[EB/OL]. [2021-12-01]. https://nepis.epa.gov/Exe/ZyPURL.cgi?Dockey=00000M2K.txt.pdf. [15] MCLEAN B J. Evolution of marketable permits: the US experience with sulfur dioxide allowance trading[J]. Int. J. Environment and Pollution, 1997, 8(1/2): 19 − 36. [16] United States Congress. Public Law 101-549(1990)[A]. Washington D. C. : United States Government Priting Office, 1993. [17] 李晓绩. 排污权交易制度研究[D]. 长春: 吉林大学, 2009.